The Real World (Part III) by: Matt Witting 10 February, 2003 |
Fulvicin - the antifungal antibiotic, which is taken at mycosis of skin, hair and nails (favus, trichophytosis, microsporia of a pilar part of the head, microsporia of smooth skin, dermatomycosis of beard and moustaches, epidermophitia of smooth skin, inguinal epidermophitia, onychomycoses ). It is effective concerning fungus of the sort Trichophyton, Microsporum, Epydermophyton, Achorionum; causes disturbance of the structure of a mitotic spindle and synthesis of a cell wall at chitin fungus, suppresses division of fungal cells in metaphase and synthesis of protein because of disruption of linking with template-RNA.
[The players]
play for men who "have come into the business for no other motive
than to exploit it for every dollar in sight." The NL "has
no apology to make for its existence or for its untarnished record
of fourteen years" because it "rescued the National Game
from destruction threatened by the dishonesty and dissipation of the
players." The owners argued that they gained little in serving
as the ethical wardens of baseball, while, thanks to the reserve rule,
the "salaries of players have more then trebled" since the
National League's inception. The owners asked the public to reject
the "overpaid players" who wanted to "again control
[baseball] for their own aggrandizement, but to [the game's] ultimate
dishonor and disintegration." "[MLB Commish
Bud Selig] should also have set up a management office to teach some
of these teams how to run their baseball businesses, because while
the playing field is unlevel and there are gross inequities inherent
to the current system, the fact is that the Brewers, Tigers, Royals,
Devil Rays and other teams are what they are for a reason -- bad management.
The A's, Reds, Astros and Giants compete every year because of good
management. The Red Sox are paying $110 million for a $70 million
team because of previous bad management." Team Salaries Here is a chart of team salaries, by sport, for the 2001 season (for MLB) or the 2001-02 season (for the NFL, NBA, and NHL). Linear trend-lines have been included. Each marked point represents a single team's salary within the league. There are subtle differences between the capped and non-capped leagues, based on this chart. All four leagues have a steep drop-off after the top team or two and before the last team or two. Only the capped leagues have a virtually flat linear progression between the two extremes, however. The trend lines for the NFL and NBA are shallower than the trend lines for MLB and the NHL and, in fact, virtually parallel each other. Baseball and hockey have a "stepped" downward progression that is much steeper than the NFL/NBA. This is dramatically evident in the MLB line where every 3-6 teams there is a steep drop to the next cluster, a trend less dramatic but equally visible for the NHL. Figure 1 illustrated that sports with some form of cap seem to have a smoother distribution of wealth, and (in numerical terms) a lesser disparity between the rich and the poor. Figure 2 shows this more clearly. It shows the single highest team payroll, the average of the top five teams, the overall league average, the average of the bottom five teams and the single lowest team payroll by league. It is interesting to note that all four leagues are "top-heavy": the difference between the top five and the league average exceeds the difference between the bottom five and league average. The following chart shows the difference between the average of the top five team salaries in each league (the second set of bars in Figure 2) and the average of all teams (the third set of bars in Fig. 2) in both numerical and percentage terms: The most highly paid teams in the capped leagues are much closer to the average team salary than they are in the un-capped leagues where the difference is greater than half the average team salary. Figure 4 shows the average of the 5 lowest team salaries subtracted from the average team salary in the league: The bottom 5 in each league are actually closer to the average salary than the top 5 are, regardless of whether the league has a cap or not. This seems to indicate that a small number of "haves" in each league are standing out from a much larger number of "have-nots" or "have-lesses". Competitive Balance In the real world a cap, soft or hard, does serve to keep the teams closer together in terms of payroll expenditures. The intent of a cap, though, is not just to restrain labor costs. Increased competition is the other key element. People in favor of salary caps and other restraints on the cost of labor argue that they will increase the competitive balance around the league, allowing small market teams to compete on equal footing with large market teams. We'll look at this argument from two angles. First is how many different teams make the Championship game/series for each league over time. More teams making the finals means more competitive balance, fewer means less. The second angle is to examine the standard deviation of the winning percentages in a league over time. Less disparity in winning percentages means more competitive balance (a four team league whose teams finish 2-4, 3-3, 3-3, 4-2 is more competitive than one whose teams finish 0-6, 3-3, 3-3, 6-0). By looking at how these two indicators vary before and after the introduction of a cap in the NFL and NBA, and by comparing those two with the NHL and MLB, we can easily determine the effectiveness of caps at creating competitive balance in the real world. We'll start with the hard-capped NFL and look at how many different teams won the Super Bowl. It's been 8 full seasons since the cap was instituted so the data is broken down into 8-year segments (Cap-era in green): The NFL, pre-cap, seemed to be somewhat cyclical. Dynasties arose and dominated for several years before collapsing. Their reigns were followed by a stretch where anyone seemed to have a chance, but then certain teams took over the league again (noticeably not the same ones as dominated earlier, for the most part). Since the onset of the cap there has been a greater variety of Super Bowl finalists and a wider range have won. No single team has dominated the league for long, even the supposedly mighty St. Louis Rams of the last 3 years. Only three of the last 18 Super Bowls have been won (in 4 tries) by teams from Chicago, LA, Houston or New York City (the 4 largest markets in the US). Of course, Houston and LA haven't had teams for most of that stretch. Based on Super Bowl finalists the NFL is seeing much more variety since the institution of the cap. Our second indicator
is the standard deviation among winning percentages in the NFL by
season. Larger numbers indicate that there is less balance because
the winning percentages vary more greatly. Based on the Super Bowl
numbers we can expect to see that the average of the standard deviation
of the 8 seasons since the cap was instituted is less than the average
of the standard deviations of the 8 years immediately preceding it. As Figure 6 shows, the numbers contradict our expectations. While the cap era numbers are closer together than the pre-cap era numbers, the difference is by 0.0218%, the equivalent of 2 pennies relative to a $100 bill. More different teams are making the Super Bowl, but the overall competitiveness of the league has not changed in the years since the cap was implemented. The years with the second and fourth highest standard deviations were under the cap, while the years with the second and fourth smallest standard deviations were pre-cap. The NFL's cap is improving parity at the very top of the league, it seems, but has done little if anything for league-wide parity statistically. In the soft-cap
NBA the situation is very different. As you recall, the cap was implemented
in full force prior to the 1984-85 season. It's been 18 full seasons
since then, so we've broken the NBA history into 9-year segments: In only one 9-year segment prior to the implementation of the cap (the 9 years featuring the Celtic dynasty of the 50's and 60's) did fewer teams win the NBA championship than have in the two segments of the cap era. More different teams have made the finals, it is true, but since the cap came into being only one NBA champion has failed to defend their crown at least once. Even more interesting is that the cap was implemented to protect smaller market teams and increase their competitiveness. The 4 largest markets in the United States are New York, Los Angeles, Chicago and Houston. In the 18 years since the cap was brought into effect, the Chicago Bulls, LA Lakers and Houston Rockets have won 14 championships (Chicago 6, LA 6 and Houston 2). Teams from New York, LA and Houston have also lost in the finals 6 times (the Knicks and Lakers twice, the Nets once and the Rockets once) for a total of 20 appearances. In the 18 years prior to the cap, the 4 largest markets only won 5 titles in 13 appearances and the only repeat champions were the smaller market Boston Celtics of 67/68 and 68/69. As we saw with
the NFL, the championships are not a perfect measurement of overall
balance, so let's look at the standard deviations for the NBA. It's
been 18 years since the inception of the NBA cap, so we're using 18
year segments, not 8. The NFL had a difference between the two of roughly .02% in favor of the cap. In the NBA the difference is just over 2.0%, and shows that the pre-cap era actually had more competitive balance. Where the NFL shows no change in competitive balance league wide and a measurable improvement in top-end competitiveness, the NBA shows a significant decrease in competitiveness both at the top and across the board. Based on these numbers the soft cap is a resounding failure at promoting parity. We've looked at
the hard-cap league (doesn't promote league-wide parity) and a soft-cap
league (apparently not effective at improving competitive balance
and may actually restrain it). Now let's look at the non-capped leagues
to see how they measure up. First up is baseball, also broken down
into 9 year segments to make comparisons easier (don't forget that
the 1904 and 1994 World Series were cancelled). Based on this data, baseball is and always has been more competitive than basketball (with or without the cap) if we look at the number of teams making the Finals and winning the World Series. It is also almost as competitive the post cap NFL at times. Despite all the uproar about the Yankees and "buying the World Series", teams from the big 4 markets have won only 6 Championships in 8 appearances in the last 18 years, fewer than basketball although still twice as many as in the NFL. Looking at league-wide
numbers also shows interesting numbers. Here are the average of the
standard deviations since the 1995 season (the inception of the most
recent salary cap: the NFL's) Despite the popular outcry against the unfairness of baseball, it is significantly more competitive league wide than basketball or football (or hockey, as we'll see in a minute). MLB also has good variety in the number of different finalists in the World Series. Despite the lack of a cap and only limited revenue sharing, Major League Baseball delivers excellent competitive balance. The sheer number of games (162) and length of the season (7 months), combined with the very small number of teams to make the playoffs (8 total, compared with 16 in hockey and basketball, and 12 in the NFL) magnify the statistically small differences between good and bad teams in baseball. The fact remains that baseball is, based on the numbers, more competitive than any of the other major sports leagues. Finally we come
to the NHL. The NHL took over the Stanley Cup prior to the 1926-27
season. Since then, here are the numbers: Despite the complaints about free agency, small market teams, rising payrolls and such the league has been more competitive over the last 20 years than it has at any time in its history, based on this criterion. Looking at the standard deviations supports this claim. The National Hockey
League has produced a wide variety of Stanley Cup finalists as well
as a very even league, overall, since the strike-shortened 1994/1995
season. Despite claims of restrictions on team spending, the two leagues with serious caps and revenue sharing show the least competitive balance league wide. The NFL number is skewed high due to the relatively small number of games they play (16 per season), while MLB is skewed low due to their very long season (162 games), but the NHL and NBA both play 82 games and the difference between them is marked. The two leagues without caps and significant revenue sharing seem to produce more balanced competition than the leagues with cost-of-labor restrictions over the last 8 years. In addition, we saw that the restrictions did little if anything to improve competition in the NFL and may have actually hurt the NBA's pursuit of parity. Player Salaries "Players
don't deserve all the money they're getting, but the owners don't
deserve it even more." "And then
we come into a year like this where we get five-year contracts - (at)
$9 million (per year). There are ways to run a business and that's
why there's going to be a lockout. Because we're not running the business
well." Proponents of restricting the price of labor in professional sports argue that salary caps, revenue sharing and other such methods will reduce player salaries. Capping the amount that teams may spend on payroll supposedly limits the ability of the owners to pay huge salaries to individual players and prevents salaries from spiraling out of control. Taking a list
of every player who started the season with a major league team, here
are the numbers on player salaries (2001-02 for the NFL and NBA, 2002
for MLB and 2002-03 for the NHL). Figure 14 lists the average salary
for each of the major leagues, the median salary (the one in the middle),
and the standard deviation on salaries (how much variation is there). Here is a listing of the top five individual salaries in each sport: The NBA is far
and away the best league for player salaries. The NFL has the lowest
average rate of pay (and doesn't have guaranteed contracts either).
It is interesting to note that the two leagues without salary caps
are the two middle ones in terms of average salary, not the highest.
Despite complaints about skyrocketing salaries in the NHL, the top
moneymaker in hockey is Jaromir Jagr of the Washington Capitals. His
salary of $11,483,333 per year would put him sixth in the NFL, sixteenth
in MLB and eighteenth in the NBA. Here's the breakdown by league of
how many players (number and as a percentage of the whole) make more
than certain amounts: Despite (or more accurately because of) being the smallest league in terms of players, the NBA has the same number of individuals making $10 million or more as the rest of the pro leagues combined. The leagues with larger team rosters have more players making under $1 million/year. Having a salary cap doesn't seem to affect how much money top end players make. Owners in all four leagues offer the top talent the most money to play for their team. To cut payroll they generally go after the mid-range players, not the stars. Even in the NFL with the hard cap most stars have their contracts re-negotiated to stall their impact on the cap, cuts tend to be less important, middle-pay range type players. The NHL's Washington Capitals are a good example of this. After signing Jaromir Jagr and Robert Lang to long term, big money deals over the last two years, they reduced payroll by trading or releasing the likes of Andrei Nikolishin, Sylvain Cote, Chris Simon and Joe Sacco. Serviceable players, yes, but older players all of whom were making more money than the Caps were happy with. They have been replaced mostly by minor-leaguers from within the Washington system and being paid close to the league minimum. The young players are competent but probably not as effective as the vets would have been, so far at least. Just like in un-capped sports, salary caps don't strongly influence the escalation of player salaries. Players perceived as stars are being paid tremendous sums in all four sports (hockey least of all) while the salaries and job status of the low end and mid range players are adjusted to compensate. The Proverbial Family of Four "The average
cost to attend a game: $303. And what do you get for these bucks?
Four tickets, two small draft beers, four small soft drinks, four
regular-sized hot dogs, parking, two game programs and two of the
least-expensive adult-sized caps. Kind of takes away your appetite,
doesn't it? That is not my idea of what constitutes an affordable
afternoon. It's hard to enjoy yourself when you keep thinking about
how many lunches you will have to skip just to get the budget back
on track." Ticket prices have increased in all the major leagues, there is no question about that. The Team Marketing Report's "Fan Cost Index" is the popular way to judge how pricey sporting events are. The survey tracks the cost of attendance for a family of four. The FCI includes: two adult average price tickets; two child average price tickets; four small soft drinks; two small beers; four hot dogs; two programs; parking; and two adult-size caps. The FCIs for the 2002 or 2002/03 seasons are: While the numbers used to come up with the FCI are certainly legitimate and the Index does give a good look at the increasing costs at the arena, it has flaws. First it assumes that the family will sit in "average price" tickets. Many teams offer discounted family packs that include most of the above items. The NHL's Capitals, for example, have the "WB50 Family Pack" that consists of 4 tickets, 4 hamburgers, 4 bags of chips, 4 medium sodas, and 4 Caps hats. It starts at $78 for the whole package but runs as high as $190 for premium side seats. The Fan Cost Index is similar to the Consumer Price Index: it measures a basket of goods, only a fraction of which are applicable to all consumers. As such it gives a good overall picture, but not a precise view of the actual state of affairs for individuals. The argument that it costs much more today to attend a game then it did 5, 10 or 20 years ago is also open to debate. Allen Sanderson is a senior lecturer in economics at the University of Chicago and senior study director at the National Opinion Research Center (NORC). When not answering the sports-and-economics questions of reporters from the Chicago Tribune to the New York Times, he teaches a two-quarter introductory economics sequence in the College, and works on NORC survey research projects related to labor markets and higher education. Here is his response to the FCI and complaints about the cost of attending baseball games from his paper "Bottom-Line Drive" (published in 1994):
Most sporting event attendees aren't families of four, either. Businesses buy tickets, groups buy tickets for outings, the most popular teams sell most of their seats to long-time season ticket holders. Another factor to consider is the concept of "good seats". The new arenas that have sprung up over the last 10 years or so generally don't have a bad seat in the house. Despite somewhat cramped quarters, they rarely have obstructed sightlines and even the top row of the upper deck in most NHL arenas is close enough to see the action. Older arenas have a higher number of less desirable seats, but the concept of the "bad seat" is not as prevalent as it was years ago. The average cost of a ticket tends to be weighted towards the upper end of the scale regardless due to the cost of club seats, premium rink-side tickets and luxury boxes. If I purchase a $150 ticket at center ice and four $25 dollar seats in the first row of the upper deck then the average ticket price for the five seats I bought is $50 thanks to the one pricey seat. Ticket prices have increased, there is no doubt, and they continue to increase. Relative to incomes, relative to purchasing power and relative to other entertainment options, however, they have actually gotten cheaper. To quote Sanderson again, "..paraphrasing Twain, it's not so much what you don't know that gets you into trouble, it's what you think you know that turns out to be wrong". Did I Do That? The Law of Unintended Consequences "It is not
from the benevolence of the butcher, or the baker, that we expect
our dinner, but from regard to their own self interest." The law of unintended
consequences, often cited but rarely defined, is that actions of people,
, organizations, and governments always have effects that are unanticipated
or "unintended." Economists and other social scientists
have heeded its power for centuries; for just as long, politicians
and popular opinion have largely ignored it. The NFL features virtually no trades in a given year. Teams generally swap draft picks when deals are made, rarely is a player actually sent from one team to another. In addition, the very early trade deadline means that few teams know what kind of players they actually need for the current season, or even if they are on track to make the playoffs at all. Given that most teams max out their cap space early, trading for an impact player is next to impossible if space under the cap must be cleared. The NBA typically sees a large number of trades, but few meaningful ones. The majority take place during the off-season, especially on draft day, and are moves for draft picks. Because of the way the NBA cap is structured, trades must be balanced in terms of salary, a difficult medium to reach. The cap is set up to encourage players to remain with one team, making it even harder to deal established vets. In MLB and the NHL trades occur regularly. They involve stars and prospects, rookies and vets, winners and losers. If a team in contention needs a switch-hitting shortstop going into the stretch drive, they can get one. If they have a surplus of young talent but aren't going to make the playoffs, a team can deal some at the deadline for a veteran to help next season. Part of the reason for this is that baseball and hockey have extensive minor league systems, making prospects a common and valuable commodity (unlike football and basketball which have no real post-draft minor league system). They also have later trade deadlines that allow teams to evaluate better their chances this year and needs for the playoffs/draft/next season. Given that there are no restraints on salaries, a team ready to make a push for the Stanley Cup might decide to spend an extra $2 mil to get a vet to help in the playoffs, depending on playoff revenues to pay for him. Salary caps were not set up to decrease the ability of teams to better themselves for the post-season/future through trades, but they have had that effect in both the NBA and NFL. Another unintended consequence of the salary caps is a phenomenon known as "salary cap hell" to those in NFL circles. As we covered earlier, teams are often encumbered with "dead money", payable to players no longer on the roster but still counting against the cap. Teams with significant dead money can't afford to sign as many experienced/quality players and suffer for it. The descent into salary cap hell is often caused by a team doing everything possible to win in one season by knowingly compromising the future. The team and fans are then forced to pay for a short period of prosperity with what can be a long stretch of mediocrity or worse. This peculiar phenomenon is not found in baseball or hockey, although it is appearing occasionally in the NBA. The Washington Wizards were unable to make much movement in the free agent market to improve their woeful team until recently. What changed? They finally found a way to get rid of Juwon Howard and his obscenely large contract, giving them enough room under the cap to sign a few decent mid-range players. Their owners made the mistake by giving Howard the huge contract, but without the cap it would have been possible to trade him (a la Albert Belle in MLB or Jaromir Jagr in the NHL) or buy out his contract so the team could have rebuilt at least two years earlier. The salary caps can make it impossible for owners/GMs to overcome their past mistakes and can penalize a team and its fans for years for one bad contract or two decent years of success (although this effect is probably more pronounced in the NBA than elsewhere given the smaller number of total players per team and hence the weight of a single large contract). An unintended consequence of revenue sharing has shown up in baseball. The owners of certain small-market teams (Kansas City, Milwaukee and Minnesota, for example) have been accused of not using the shared revenue to improve their teams. Despite the fact that each receives a significant sum from the revenue sharing pot, only Minnesota has been competitive in recent years. The Twins have succeeded on great drafting, quality pitching, and exceptional defense from young players. As their players get older and more recognized it will be interesting to see if their owner antes up to keep them. Several owners of big market, high profit teams allege (and are supported by a variety of academics, sports writers and business journals) that some of those owners simply pocket the shared revenue, rather then using the money to make their ballparks/ball clubs more competitive. This has caused a rift among owners, has angered fans, and is partially responsible for the Yankees creation of the YES! TV network in New York. Socialism In The American Pastime? "This [revenue-sharing]
is socialism at work and baseball is still a free-enterprise sport." \So"cial*ism\,
n. [Cf. F. socialisme.] A theory or system of social reform which
contemplates a complete reconstruction of society, with a more just
and equitable distribution of property and labor. It is unlikely
that a revolution is coming from the laborers in any of the four major
sports, so calling a salary cap or revenue-sharing plan "socialist"
takes things a little far. After all, according to Marx a socialist
state is achieved after the revolution of the proletariat prior to
developing a fully communist state of affairs. On the other hand,
fans are certainly demanding change and they, perhaps more than the
athletes, deserve the proletariat label.
Mr. Lansky does
have a point, despite the obvious holes in his statement; some employers
do limit the earnings of their employees. He is applying his brush
a little too broadly, however, as government employees are not technically
limited in their earnings. Government employees (including policemen
and public school teachers) can always quit and go do almost exactly
the same job in the private sector where salaries are generally not
capped. As my daytime disguise is that of a mild-mannered contractor
with the US government I can confirm this: the vast majority of my
co-workers are former US government employees or military personnel
who have retired and gone to work for our company for better money.
One was immediately signed on as an outside consultant to do the same
job he did while in uniform, but he now gets more money to do it and
lets his hair grow an extra 1/2 inch. A professional athlete in North
America does not have the option to quit and go elsewhere if they
wish to continue in the exciting Professional Hockey Player career
field; they are stuck with one major league. There are countless opportunities
for accountants, analysts, network technicians and current/former
servicemen in the public and private sector but there are very few
outside the big leagues for professional athletes of that caliber.
Given that the government is constantly bemoaning the lack of qualified,
intelligent applicants for its innumerable open positions I'd say
that this is an example of why limiting individual salaries is a bad
thing, but that is a personal opinion. In the end salary caps as they
exist today do not limit individual salaries effectively, as we have
already shown. Want to share your opinion on this piece? Visit the boards and make yourself heard, insult the author, or see what others have to say. Copyright Matthew Witting and WashingtonHockey.com. Unauthorized reproduction or redistribution in whole and in part is prohibited. Please Clotrimazole troche teachingBuy bimatoprost canadaif you have questions or wish to use any part elsewhere. |